Abstract
Here
is an examination of Chinese institutional change and why the debate
necessitates a new approach toward studying global economic divergence, one
which focuses on a separation of mathematical evaluations rather than
technological advancement. Great Divergence discussions and debate are
historiographical disciplines that examine state formation in East Asia and its
cultural evolution in juxtaposition with parts of Western Europe. The advent of
steam power and other technologies in production and transport allowed Britain
and other parts of Europe to extend their momentum past Malthusian restraints
and separate themselves from “poorer” countries, or so it was largely held in
academic circles. But recently, the “California School” of historians like R.
Bin Wong, Kenneth Pomeranz, and Andre Gunder Frank contend that China shared
several surprising similarities in proto-industrial development with their
Western counterparts throughout Eurasia as late as 1750. Dynamics of political,
economic, and cultural change that have been taken up by historians of Early
Modern industrialization favored a Eurocentric approach to history. So, who is
right? My article will add impetus to a new argument by focusing on separate
commentary from historians studying Europe’s transition to an Arabic numeral
system and China’s insistence on traditional numeric methods. Modernity
originated from a new abacus based on a ten-place system calculating numbers as
large as 1027, the year some purport it to have first been taught in Europe. Contemporary
literacy materials are built on similar education standards. Before 1815, state
formation in Europe and China resembled each other because of this and in the
years after, Big History settled what had been lost when Chinese labor
migration and diaspora to the New World made a hybrid world economy
unmistakable.